0801-1/1

"Sogo-shosha" in Japan

 

  The eighth annual meeting of the Business History Society of Japan was

held at the Kuansei-Gakuin University in the City of Nishinomiya on

the eighteenth and nineteenth of November, 1972. Following the fourteen

reports on free topics on the first day, the six papers on "Sogo-shosha"

were read on the second day.

  Professor Mataji Miyamoto of the Kuansei-Gakuin University, who was

one of the organizers of this common topic session, pointed out that the

over-all development of Sogo-shosha was due to the economic circumstances

in the post World War II Japan and  the dominant role  in the foreign

trade before World War II was played rather by the merchants who were

specialized respectively in the import and export of textiles, drugs,  raw

cottons,  cotton yarns,  irons and sometimes in Mexican dollars.  But the

professor  Miyamoto seemed to deny neither the importance of  the

forerunners of Sogo-shosha such as the Mitsui, Mitsubishi, Suzuki and

lwai  trading companies nor the fact that some of the warehousemen in

Osaka were already general merchants in a sense that they traded in the

varied items of the goods mentioned above.

  Professor Yasuo Mishima of the Konan University traced the course of

development of the Mitsubishi Trading Co. First, he emphasized that the

trading activity of the Mitsubishi Combine started in the selling of the

coal and copper produced within themselves and it was not until  1920s

that the Mitsubishi Trading Co.  firmly established their trading business

in the import of raw cotton and wool and in the export of raw silk and

cotton yarn.  But since the turn of the century the Trading Department

of the Mitsubishi Co.  had become active in exporting paper, glass, beer

and other products of their manufacturing departments and subsidiaries

and before the World War I they had already established the world-wide

trading network.  Professor Mishima also described in details the role of

Mitsubishi Trading Co. in introducing the newest industrial technologies

from Germany, England, United States and other developed industrial

countries.

  Professor Yosio Togai of the Senshu University commented on the

Mitsui Trading Co.  in contrast with the Mitsubishi Trading Co.  He

agreed with Professor Mishima in that the Mitsuibishi was much behind

the Mitsui in general trading activities and pointed out that the trading

activities of Mitsubishi had been most active in purchasing abroad the

machines, equipments and raw material for the heavy industrial produc-

tion within Mitsubishi combines themselves, whereas the Mitsui  Trading

Co. dealt in large quantity of the light industrial products mostly of the

independent producers.

  Professor Yoshio Katsura of the University of Kobe read a paper

elaborated on the Suzuki Co.  that was once the  second largest trading

company in Japan and bankrupted in 1927. Suzuki Co. started in dealing

with the camphor, sugar and other products in Formosa and on the

windfall profit  accumulated during the boom of  World  War  I they

were aggressively diversified into manufacturing activities and became to

control 74 subsidiary firms.  Professor Katsura pointed out  that such a

expansion of industrial activities was highly depended on the information

which the Suzuki Co. gathered through their world-wide trading network

and the company could thus become a pioneer in the rayon and synthetic

anmonium industries in Japan.

  Professor Yotaro Sakudo of the University of Osaka reported on the

development of lwai Co. which had developed in Kwansai district side by

side with the Suzuki Co. as one of the industrial organizers in Japan before

World War II. lwai Co. originated in a "tomotsuya": a warehouseman

who traded goods imported through the port of Nagasaki before Meiji

Restoration.  They gradually diversified the items of their dealing with

foreign merchants in the settlements and at the end of the nineteenth

century ventured into the direct import from a London merchant. At the

beginning of this century they set up and controlled the several firms

in the celluloid, soda, paint, iron plate, wool-spinning and other industries

and as a trading firm they came to share with other four firms the

products of the Yawata Iron and Steel Works, the largest government

mill in Japan.  Professor Sakudo emphasized that the  deversification of

the lwai Co. was, in comparison with the Suzuki Co, was much more

rationally restricted, controlling less than 10 industrial firms.

  Professor Katsutoshi Uchida of the Doshisha University who is primarily

an economist on foreign trade stood on the view-point that the Sogo-shosha

was entirely the product of the post-World-War-ll Japan. He divided the

history of Sogo-shosha into two phases.  On the first stage since 1955

they developed as the marketing channels for the heavy industrial products

and on the second stage when the Japanese economy turned to dis-heavy-

industrialization they tried to find their outlet in the new functions such

as system-organizers, developers, etc.  Professor Uchida also emphasized

that we should reconsider the role of Sogo-shosha as a creator of the

inter-firm credit that has been one of the unique and important features

of business finance in post-World-War-ll Japan.

  The final speaker, Professor Kozo Yamanura gave the audiance a

theoretical interpretation of the Sogo-shosha. He analysed the meaning of

the economic functions of Sogo-shosha, emphasizing and combinining the

three functions of reducing transaction cost, economies of scale and saving

of social cost.  Applying such theoretical frame work, Professor Yamamura

shillfully explained why  the  trading organization such  as Sogo-shosha

developed only in Japan and why the late-comer Sogo-shosha who started

during the boom of World War I got into bankrupt. Professor Yamamura

sucessfully elucidated the emergence of Sogo-shosha by taking into his

theoretical frame-work the subsidiary functions of Sogo-shosha such as

shipping, marine insurance and foreign exchange businesses.

(Editor in Chief, Keiichiro Nakagawa)

 

 

0802-1/3

FORMATION OF OPERATING ORGANIZATION

IN ENGLISH RAILWAY

Fukushima University

Takeshi Yuzawa

 

  It is possible to consider the growing process of the formation  of  the

operating organization in English railway in the following two aspects.

The first is the process brought forth by the running of railway carriages,

which made it necessary to form some primitive organization.   This

organisation gradually developed with the subdivision of the existing

functions and the creation of the new functions, and with precise definition

of the workers' duty.

  The second is the process enforced by the through-traffic, which neces

sarily led to the establishment of the Railway Clearing House and to the

decision on the standard gauge.   Through this process the operating

organization became more unified and standardized in major railway com-

panies except G. W. R. which adopted the broad gauge.

  The size and scope of the operating organization was limited at first.

It was obliged to depend upon the contracting System in doing such work

as maintenance of permanent way, loading and unloading goods,  and

repair of carriages.  But with the increased capacity of management the

company, being confronted with the difficult problem of ensuring safety

at limited expenses, began to exercise direct control over work as men-

tioned above.

 

 

0802-2/3

BARGAINING PROCESS BETWEEN JERSEY

STANDARD AND LG.FARBEN, 1920-1930.

Tohoku University

Eisuke Daito

 

  In 1925, with the intention of joining hands in marketing of synthetic

gasoline, B. A. S.F. began to approach Jersey Standard.   Though Jersey

held a different view on immediate commercial value of coal hydrogenation

process, Jersey appreciated its great potential and decided to buy the

patent right of this process.

  The purpose of this paper is to analyze the inter-action of these two

companies with the aid of the theory of bargaining.  Whole process can

be divided into several stages.  The further the negociation proceeded,

the more subjects were taken up for discussion.  As time passed by, each

party percieved the other party's aims more accurately.

  In those days, new petro-chemical industry were emerging between chemi

cal and oil industry.  Having rather limited interests in this new fields,

Jersey admitted the prefered position of 1. G. Farben in chemical industry.

And at last, they concluded a series of contracts which contained many

provisions for co-operation in braod commercial and technical fields.

 

 

0802-3/3

THE ENTREPRENEURSHIP IN PIOPLE'S CHINA

Asia University

Tien-yi Yang

 

  In any economic system not in a state of complete stagnation, there

must be somebody exercising the abilities to see new economic possibilities,

the foresight to develop them, and the courage to take the necessary risks-

-the talents of the entrepreneur. Mao Tse-tung has always emphasized the

importance of entreneurship.  This is often obscured for the Western

reader only by the fact that in the West people think of entrepreneurship

as a characteristic of free market economies, and they do not even attempt

to study entrepreneurship in socialist countries.

  Mao's entrepreneur, however, is not the individual per se, but the col-

lective, or more precisely individuals operating in collective economies.

In many examples of good Maoist-type enterprises, there is almost always

one named individual, or a small group of individuals, who have taken

the initiative in a new development, worked out the idea, embraced the

effective forethought, and persuaded the collective to adopt it.  The aim

is not of course the maximization of individual nrofit but the maximiza-

tion of collective production.  These are the qualities of the heroic leaders

of the Taching Oilfield, the Tachai Production Brigade, and of a thousand

other economic enterprises, industrial and agricultural, which have been

presented as models of Maoist organization.

  Mao sees the education of peasants as the fundamental problem of the

Chinese economy, and considers that economic growth as well as revolution

must depend on the masses of the people and on everybody going into

action, not depending on a few people issuing orders.   Therefore,  his

strategy of developent is to bring peasants and local initiative more into

play and, under the unified planning of the central government, let the

localities do more.  Given the one basic assumption that China's problems

can only be radically solved by collective enterprise, there leaves no doubt

that entrepreneurship within the collective organization is the keystone of

Mao's hopes of rapid development, and a major object of educating peasants,

sons into modern producers.  Surely, maximizing these qualities within

that system is one of Mao's greatest and most constant preocupation in

the economic field.

 

 

0803-1/3

NEEDS FOR EDUCATION IN COMMERCE

IN THE LATER MEIJI PERIOD:

THE ROLE OF TAMEYUKI AMANO

Kazuo Sugiyama

 

  The author tried to elucidate the points of criticism by the Japanese

businessmen on the contemporary education in commerce, taking up the

case of Tameyuki Amano, a famous Meiji economist, teacher and publisher.

Amano emphasized the practcalization of school education in Japan throngh

his writing and promotive activities.  He was afraid that the business

activities in Japan had been obstructed by the shortage of able  young

managerial talents, and emphasized the urgent needs for education massive

would be salalied managers.  Especially he expected that the high schools,

colleges and universities in Japan should bring up a large number of middle

management and young clerical staffs.

 

 

0803-2/3

RETAIL TRADING IN THE INDUSTRIAL

REVOLUTION IN ENGLAND

Hiroki Kakimoto

 

  It is often said that the  modernization  of  distribution  system  would

usually lag behind industrialization.  However, in British economic history,

there are two contradictory views of the problem: whether or not the

Industrial Revolution in England was accompanied by a retail revolution.

In examining this debate, we must consider the retailing of this period

from the side of consumers who intervened into the distribution system.

For example, the Rochdale Pioneers established the base from which the

true modernization of distribution system started.

 

 

0803-3/3

MANAGEMENT IN THE DECLINING

SILK-SPOOLING INDUSTRY:

THE CASES OF THE KATAKURA

AND THE GUNZE COMPANIES

Mitsuo Fujii

 

 The silk-spooling industry was one of the important traditional industries

in Japan, developed since before the Meiji Restoration.  Before World War

II it developed in many localities as a key export industry and accerelated

the overall development of capitalistic production in Japan by earning

handsome foreign exchange.  However, after World War II, the conditions

of the industry changed conspicuously.  The new synthetic fibres, especially

"nylon" took the place of raw silk as a raw material of the U.S. full-

fashioned hosiery industry.  On the other hand, the rapid economic growth,

especially the development of heavy and chemical industries, pulled apart

laboreres from the toilsome manual labor in the silk-spooling industry.

  Many silk-spooling firms have closed their factories and diversified their

investment into many other industries.  Some of them have been going

forward to invest in foreign countries, such asBrasilandParaguary. The

Katakura and the Gunze have taken the lead in such new development.